what is economics explain the nature and scope of economics and what is economics game theory
WilliamsMcmahon,United States,Professional
Published Date:20-07-2017
Your Website URL(Optional)
Comment
Chapter 1
What Is Economics?
Fast-Food Economics
You are just beginning your study of economics, but let us fast-forward to the end of your first economics
course. How will your study of economics affect the way you see the world?
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
6 The final exam is over. You are sitting at a restaurant table, waiting for your friends to arrive. The place is
busy and loud as usual. Looking around, you see small groups of people sitting and talking animatedly.
Most of the customers are young; this is not somewhere your parents visit very often. At the counter,
people line up to buy food. You watch a woman choose some items from the menu and hand some notes
and coins to the young man behind the counter. He is about the same age as you, and you think that he is
probably from China. After a few moments, he hands her some items, and she takes them to a table next
to yours.
Where are you? Based on this description, you could be almost anywhere in the world. This particular
fast-food restaurant is a Kentucky Fried Chicken, or KFC, but it could easily have been a McDonald’s, a
Burger King, or any number of other fast-food chains. Restaurants like this can be found in Auckland,
Buenos Aires, Cairo, Denver, Edinburgh, Frankfurt, Guangzhou, and nearly every other city in the world.
Here, however, the menu is written in French, and the customer paid in euros (€). Welcome to Paris.
While you are waiting, you look around you and realize that you are not looking at the world in the same
way that you previously did. The final exam you just completed was for an economics course, and—for
good or for ill—it has changed the way you understand the world. Economics, you now understand, is all
around you, all the time.
1.1 Microeconomics in a Fast-Food Restaurant
L E A R N I N G O B JE C T I V E
1. What kinds of problems do we study in microeconomics?
You watch another customer go to the counter and place an order. She purchases some fried chicken,
an order of fries, and a Coca-Cola. The cost is €10. She hands over a bill and gets the food in
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
7 exchange. It’s a simple transaction; you have witnessed exchanges like it thousands of times before.
Now, though, you think about the fact that this exchange has made both the customer and the store
better off than they were previously. The customer has voluntarily given up money to get food.
Presumably, she would do this only if having the food makes her happier than having the €10. KFC,
meanwhile, voluntarily gave up the food to get the €10. Presumably, the managers of the store would
sell the food only if they benefit from the deal as well. They are willing to give up something of value
(their food) in exchange for something else of value (the customer’s money).
Think for a moment about all the transactions that could have taken place but did not. For the same
€10, the customer could have bought two orders of fried chicken. But she didn’t. So even though you
have never met the person, you know something about her. You know that—at this moment at least—
she prefers having a Coca-Cola, fries, and one order of fried chicken to having two orders of fried
chicken. You also know that she prefers having that food to any number of other things she could
have bought with those euros, such as a movie theater ticket, some chocolate bars, or a book.
From your study of economics, you know that her decision reflects two different factors. The first is
her tastes. Each customer likes different items on the menu. Some love the spicy fried chicken;
others dislike it. There is no accounting for differences in tastes. The second is what she can afford.
She has a budget in mind that limits how much she is willing to spend on fast food on a given day.
Her decision about what to buy comes from the interaction between her tastes and her budget.
Economists have built a rich and complicated theory of decision making from this basic idea.
You look back at the counter and to the kitchen area behind it. The kitchen, you now know, is an
example of a production process that takes inputs and produces output. Some of the inputs are
perhaps obvious, such as basic ingredients like raw chicken and cooking oil. Before you took the
economics course, you might have thought only about those ingredients. Now you know that there
are many more inputs to the production process, including the following:
The building housing the restaurant
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
8 The tables and chairs inside the room
The people working behind the cash register and in the kitchen
The people working at KFC headquarters managing the outlets in Paris
The stoves, ovens, and other equipment in the kitchen used to cook the food
The energy used to run the stoves, the ovens, the lighting, and the heat
The recipes used to convert the ingredients into a finished product
The outputs of KFC are all the items listed on the menu. And, you realize, the restaurant provides not
only the food but also an additional service, which is a place where you can eat the food.
Transforming these inputs (for example, tables, chickens, people, recipes) into outputs is not easy.
Let us examine one output—for example, an order of fried chicken. The production process starts
with the purchase of some uncooked chicken. A cook then adds some spices to the chicken and places
it in a vat of very hot oil in the huge pots in the kitchen. Once the chicken is cooked, it is placed in a
box for you and served to you at the counter. That production process uses, to a greater or lesser
degree, almost all the inputs of KFC. The person responsible for overseeing this transformation is the
manager. Of course, she doesn’t have to analyze how to do this herself; the head office provides a
detailed organizational plan to help her.
KFC management decides not only what to produce and how to produce it but also how much to
charge for each item. Before you took your economics course, you probably gave very little thought to
where those prices on the menu came from. You look at the price again: €5 for an order of fried
chicken. Just as you were able to learn some things about the customer from observing her decision,
you realize that you can also learn something about KFC. You know that KFC wouldn’t sell an order
of fried chicken at that price unless it was able to make a profit by doing so. For example, if a piece of
raw chicken cost €6, then KFC would obviously make a loss. So the price charged must be greater
than the cost of producing the fried chicken.
KFC can’t set the price too low, or it would lose money. It also can’t set the price too high. What
would happen if KFC tried to charge, say, €100 for an order of chicken? Common sense tells you that
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
9 no one would buy it at that price. Now you understand that the challenge of pricing is to find a
balance: KFC needs to set the price high enough to earn a good profit on each order sold but not so
high that it drives away too many customers. In general, there is a trade-off: as the price increases,
each piece sold brings in more revenue, but fewer pieces are sold. Managers need to understand this
trade-off between price and quantity, which economists call demand. It depends on many things,
most of which are beyond the manager’s control. These include the income of potential customers,
the prices charged in alternative restaurants nearby, the number of people who think that going to
KFC is a cool thing to do, and so on.
The simple transaction between the customer and the restaurant was therefore the outcome of many
economic choices. You can see other examples of economics as you look around you—for example,
you might know that the workers earn relatively low wages; indeed, they may very well be earning
minimum wage. Across the street, however, you see a very different kind of establishment: a fancy
restaurant. The chef there is also preparing food for customers, but he undoubtedly earns a much
higher wage than KFC cooks.
Before studying economics, you would have found it hard to explain why two cooks should earn such
different amounts. Now you notice that most of the workers at KFC are young—possibly students
trying to earn a few euros a month to help support them through college. They do not have years of
experience, and they have not spent years studying the art of cooking. The chef across the street,
however, has chosen to invest years of his life training and acquiring specialized skills and, as a
result, earns a much higher wage.
The well-heeled customers leaving that restaurant are likewise much richer than those around you at
KFC. You could probably eat for a week at KFC for the price of one meal at that restaurant. Again,
you used to be puzzled about why there are such disparities of income and wealth in society—why
some people can afford to pay €200 for one meal while others can barely afford the prices at KFC.
Your study of economics has revealed that there are many causes: some people are rich because, like
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
10 the skilled chef, they have abilities, education, and experience that allow them to command high
wages. Others are rich because of luck, such as those born of wealthy parents.
Everything we have discussed in this section—the production process, pricing decisions, purchase
decisions, and the employment and career choices of firms and workers—are examples of what we
study in the part of economics called microeconomics. Microeconomics is about the behavior of
individuals and firms. It is also about how these individuals and firms interact with each other
through markets, as they do when KFC hires a worker or when a customer buys a piece of fried
chicken. When you sit in a fast-food restaurant and look around you, you can see microeconomic
decisions everywhere.
KE Y T A K E A W A Y
In microeconomics, we study the decisions of individual entities, such as households and firms. We also
study how households and firms interact with each other.
C H E C K I N G Y O U R U N D E R S T A N D I N G
1. List three microeconomic decisions you have made today.
1.2 Macroeconomics in a Fast-Food Restaurant
L E A R N I N G O B JE C T I V E
1. What kinds of problems do we study in macroeconomics?
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
11
The economic decisions you witness inside Kentucky Fried Chicken (KFC) are only a few examples of
the vast number of economic transactions that take place daily across the globe. People buy and sell
goods and services. Firms hire and lay off workers. Governments collect taxes and spend the
revenues that they receive. Banks accept deposits and make loans. When we think about the overall
impact of all these choices, we move into the realm of macroeconomics. Macroeconomics is the
study of the economy as a whole.
While sitting in KFC, you can also see macroeconomic forces at work. Inside the restaurant, some
young men are sitting around talking and looking at the newspaper. It is early afternoon on a
weekday, yet these individuals are not working. Like many other workers in France and around the
world, they recently lost their jobs. Across the street, there are other signs that the economy is not
healthy: some storefronts are boarded up because many businesses have recently been forced to
close down.
You know from your economics class that the unemployed workers and closed-down businesses are
the visible signs of the global downturn, or recession, that began around the middle of 2008. In a
recession, several things typically happen. One is that the total production of goods and services in a
country decreases. In many countries, the total value of all the goods and services produced was
lower in 2008 than it was in 2007. A second typical feature of a recession is that some people lose
their jobs, and those who don’t have jobs find it more difficult to find new employment. And a third
feature of most recessions is that those who do still have jobs are unlikely to see big increases in their
wages or salaries. These recessionary features are interconnected. Because people have lower income
and perhaps because they are nervous about the future, they tend to spend less. And because firms
are finding it harder to sell their products, they are less likely to invest in building new factories. And
when fewer factories are being built, there are fewer jobs available both for those who build factories
and for those who work in them.
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
12 Down the street from KFC, a large construction project is visible. An old road and a nearby bridge are
in the process of being replaced. The French government finances projects such as these as a way to
provide more jobs and help the economy recover from the recession. The government has to finance
this spending somehow. One way that governments obtain income is by taxing people. KFC
customers who have jobs pay taxes on their income. KFC pays taxes on its profits. And customers pay
taxes when they buy their food.
Unfortunately for the government, higher taxes mean that people and firms have less income to
spend. But to help the economy out of a recession, the government would prefer people to spend
more. Indeed, another response to a recession is to reduce taxes. In the face of the recession, the
Obama administration in the United States passed a stimulus bill that both increased government
spending and reduced taxes. Before you studied macroeconomics, this would have seemed quite
mysterious. If the government is taking in less tax income, how is it able to increase spending at the
same time? The answer, you now know, is that the government borrows the money. For example, to
pay for the 787 billion stimulus bill, the US government issued new debt. People and institutions
(such as banks), both inside and outside the United States, buy this debt—that is, they lend to the
government.
There is another institution—called the monetary authority—that purchases government debt. It has
specific names in different countries: in the United States, it is called the Federal Reserve Bank; in
Europe, it is called the European Central Bank; in Australia, it is called the Reserve Bank of
Australia; and so on. When the US government issues more debt, the Federal Reserve Bank
purchases some of it. The Federal Reserve Bank has the legal authority to create new money (in
effect, to print new currency) and then to use that to buy government debt. When it does so, the
currency starts circulating in the economy. Similarly, decisions by the European Central Bank lead to
the circulation of the euro notes and coins you saw being used to purchase fried chicken.
The decisions of the monetary authority have a big impact on the economy as well. When the
European Central Bank decides to put more euros into circulation, this has the effect of reducing
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
13 interest rates, which means it becomes cheaper for individuals to get a student loan or a mortgage,
and it is cheaper for firms to buy new machinery and build new factories. Typically, another
consequence is that the euro will become less valuable relative to other currencies, such as the US
dollar. If you are planning a trip to the United States now that your class is finished, you had better
hope that the European Central Bank doesn’t increase the number of euros in circulation. If it does,
it will be more expensive for you to buy US dollars.
Today, the world’s economies are highly interconnected. People travel from country to country.
Goods are shipped around the world. If you were to look at the labels on the clothing worn by the
customers in KFC, you would probably find that some of the clothes were manufactured in China,
perhaps some in Malaysia, some in France, some in the United States, some in Guatemala, and so on.
Information also moves around the world. The customer sitting in the corner using a laptop might be
in the process of transferring money from a Canadian bank account to a Hong Kong account; the
person at a neighboring table using a mobile phone might be downloading an app from a web server
in Illinois. This globalization brings many benefits, but it means that recessions can be global as well.
Your study of economics has taught you one more thing: the idea that you can take a trip to the
United States would have seemed remarkable half a century ago. Despite the recent recession, the
world is a much richer place than it was 25, or 50, or 100 years ago. Almost everyone in KFC has a
mobile phone, and some people are using laptops. Had you visited a similar fast-food restaurant 25
years ago, you would not have seen people carrying computers and phones. A century ago, there was,
of course, no such thing as KFC; automobiles were still a novelty; and if you cut your finger on the
sharp metal edge of a table, you ran a real risk of dying from blood poisoning. Understanding why
world economies have grown so spectacularly—and why not all countries have shared equally in this
growth—is one of the big challenges of macroeconomics.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
14 In macroeconomics, we study the economy as a whole to understand why economies grow and why they
sometimes experience recessions. We also study the effects of different kinds of government policy on
the overall economy.
C H E C K I N G Y O U R U N D E R S T A N D I N G
1. If the government and the monetary authority think that the economy is growing too fast, what could they
do to slow down the economy?
1.3 What Is Economics, Really?
L E A R N I N G O B JE C T I V E
1. What methods do economists use to study the world?
Economists take their inspiration from exactly the kinds of observations that we have discussed.
Economists look at the world around them—from the transactions in fast-food restaurants to the
policies of central banks—and try to understand how the economic world works. This means that
economics is driven in large part by data. In microeconomics, we look at data on the choices made by
firms and households. In macroeconomics, we have access to a lot of data gathered by governments
and international agencies. Economists seek to describe and understand these data.
But economics is more than just description. Economists also build models to explain these data and
make predictions about the future. The idea of a model is to capture the most important aspects of
the behavior of firms (like KFC) and individuals (like you). Models are abstractions; they are not rich
enough to capture all dimensions of what people do. Yet a good model, for all its simplicity, is still
capable of explaining economic data.
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
15 And what do we do with this understanding? Much of economics is about policy evaluation. Suppose
your national government has a proposal to undertake a certain policy—for example, to cut taxes,
build a road, or increase the minimum wage. Economics gives us the tools to assess the likely effects
of such actions and thus to help policymakers design good public policies.
This is not really what you thought economics was going to be about when you walked into your first
class. Back then, you didn’t know much about what economics was. You had a vague thought that
maybe your economics class would teach you how to make money. Now you know that this is not
really the point of economics. You don’t have any more ideas about how to get rich than you did
when you started the class. But your class has taught you something about how to make better
decisions and has given you a better understanding of the world that you live in. You have started to
think like an economist.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y
Economists gather data about the world and then build models to explain those data and make
predictions.
C H E C K I N G Y O U R U N D E R S T A N D I N G
1. Suppose you were building a model of pricing at KFC. Which of the following factors would you want
to make sure to include in your model? Which factors do you think would be irrelevant?
a. the age of the manager making the pricing decisions
b. the price of chicken
c. the number of customers who come to the store on a typical day
d. the price of apples
e. the kinds of restaurants nearby
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
16 1.4 End-of-Chapter Material
In Conclusion
Economics is all around us. We all make dozens of economic decisions every day—some big, some small.
Your decisions—and those of others—shape the world we live in. In this book, we will help you develop an
understanding of economics by looking at examples of economics in the everyday world. Our belief is that
the best way to study economics is to understand how economists think about such examples.
With this in mind, we have organized our book rather differently from most economics textbooks. It is
built not around the theoretical concepts of economics but around different applications—economic
illustrations as you encounter them in your own life or see them in the world around you. As you read this
book, we will show you how economists analyze these illustrations, introducing you to the tools of
economics as we proceed. After you have read the whole book, you will have been introduced to all the
fundamental tools of economics, and you will also have seen them in action. Most of the tools are used in
several different applications, thus allowing you to practice using them and gain a deeper understanding
of how they work.
You can see this organization at work in our table of contents. In fact, there are two versions of the table of
contents so that both students and instructors can easily see how the book is organized. The student table
of contents focuses on the applications and the questions that we address in each chapter. The instructor
table of contents lists the theoretical concepts introduced in each chapter so that instructors can easily see
how economic theory is developed and used in the book.
We have also gathered all the tools of economics into a toolkit. You will see many links to this toolkit as
you read the book. You can refer to the toolkit as needed when you want to be reminded of how a tool
works, and you can also use it as a study aid when preparing for exams and quizzes.
E X E R C I S E S
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
17 1. A map is a model constructed by geographers and cartographers. Like an economic model, it is a
simplified representation of reality. Suppose you have a map of your hometown in front of you. Think of
one question about your town that you could answer using the map. Think of another question about
your town for which the map would be useless.
2. Which of the following questions do you think would be studied by a macroeconomist and which by a
microeconomist? (Note: we don’t expect you to be able to answer all these questions yet.)
a. What should the European Central Bank do about increasing prices in Europe?
b. What happens to the price of ice cream in the summer?
c. Should you take out a student loan to pay for college?
d. What happens when the US government cuts taxes and pays for these tax cuts by borrowing
money?
e. What would happen to the prices of computers if Apple and Microsoft merged into a single firm?
Economics Detective
1. Look at a newspaper on the Internet. Find a news story about macroeconomics. How do you know that it is
about macroeconomics? Find a news story about microeconomics. How do you know that it is about
microeconomics?
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
18
Chapter 2
Microeconomics in Action
This chapter doesn't have an introduction. Please click "Next" to continue to the first section, or
select from the Table of Contents to the left.
2.1 Four Examples of Microeconomics
L E A R N I N G O B JE C T I V E S
1. What are two ways that you make economic choices all the time?
2. How do economists think about the way people react to a change in a rule?
3. What is the role of markets in an economy?
Here are four short and diverse illustrations of microeconomics you might encounter: deciding what
to do with your time and money, buying or selling on eBay, visiting a large city, and reading about a
soccer game. After you have finished your study of microeconomics, you will see these concepts very
differently from the way you see them now. You may not know it, but your everyday life is filled with
microeconomics in action.
Your Time and Money
Wouldn’t you rather be doing something else with your time right now, instead of reading an economics
textbook? You could be surfing on the Internet, reading blogs, or updating your Facebook profile. You
could be reading a novel or watching television. You could be out with friends. But you aren’t. You have
made a choice—a decision—to spend time reading this chapter.
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
19 Your choice is an economic one. Economics studies how we cope with competing demands for our time,
money, and other resources. You have only 24 hours each day, so your time is limited. Each day you have
to divide up this time among the things you like or need to do: sleeping, eating, working, studying,
reading, playing video games, hanging out in your local coffee shop, and so on. Every time you decide to
do one thing instead of another, you have made an economic decision. As you study economics, you will
learn about how you and other people make such choices, and you will also learn how to do a better job
when making these decisions.
Money is also a limited resource. You undoubtedly have many things you would like to buy if money were
no object. Instead you must choose among all the different things you like because your money—or, more
precisely, your income—is a limited resource. Every time you buy something, be it a T-shirt, a breakfast
bagel, or a new computer, you are choosing to forgo something else you could have bought instead. Again,
these are economic decisions. Economics is about how you make choices. Whenever there is a limited
resource—be it your time, the amount of oil reserves in the world, or tickets to the Super Bowl—and
decisions to be made about how to use that resource, then economics is there to help. Indeed, the
fundamental definition of economics is that it is the study of how we, as individuals and as a society,
allocate our limited resources among possible alternative uses.
eBay and craigslist
Suppose you want to buy an MP3 player. There are many ways you can do this. You can go to a local store.
You can look for stores on the Internet. You can also visit sites such as eBay (http://www.ebay.com) or
craigslist (http://www.craigslist.org). eBay is an online auction site, meaning that you can look for an
MP3 player and then bid against other potential buyers. The site craigslist is like an online version of the
classified advertisements in a newspaper, so you can look to see if someone in your town or city is selling
the player you want to buy. You can also use these sites if you want to sell something. Maybe you have
some old baseball cards you want to sell. Perhaps you have a particular skill (for example, web design),
and you want to sell your services. Then you can use sites such as eBay or craigslist as a seller instead of as
a buyer.
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
20 We have said that economics is about deciding how to use your limited resources. It is also about how we
interact with one another, and, more precisely, how we trade with one another. Adam Smith, the founder
of modern economics, observed that humans are the only animal that makes bargains: “Nobody ever saw
1
a dog make a fair and deliberate exchange of one bone for another with another dog.” Barter or trade—
the exchange of goods and services and money—is central to the world we live in today.
Economists often talk about trade taking place in markets. Some exchanges do literally take place in
markets—such as a farmers’ market where local growers bring produce to sell. Economists use the term
more generally, though: a market is any institution that allows us to exchange one thing for another. Sites
such as eBay and craigslist create markets in which we can transact. Normally, we exchange goods or
services for money. Sometimes we exchange one good or service for another. Sometimes we exchange one
type of money for another.
Most of the time, nobody forces you to buy anything, so when you give up some money in return for an
MP3 player, you are presumably happier after the transaction than before. (There are some exceptions, of
course. Can you think of any cases where you are forced to engage in an economic transaction?) Most of
the time, nobody forces you to sell anything, so when you give up your time in return for some money, you
are presumably happier after the transaction than before. Leaving aside the occasional mistake or the
occasional regret, nearly every voluntary transaction makes both participants better off. Markets matter
because they are a means for people to become happier.
Breathing the Air
Welcome to Mexico City It is a wonderful place in many respects. But not in every way: from the picture
2
you can see that Mexico City has some of the most polluted skies in the world.
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
21 Mexico City was not always so polluted. Sadly, economic growth and population growth, together with the
peculiarities of geography and climate, have combined to make its air quality among the worst you will
encounter anywhere. Other cities around the world, from Beijing to Los Angeles, also experience
significant air pollution, reducing the quality of life and bringing with it health risks and other costs.
It is hard to understand economists talking about the beauty and power of markets when you cannot
breathe the air. So what is going wrong in Mexico City? Is it not full of people carrying out trades that
make them better off? The problem is that transactions sometimes affect other people besides the buyer
and the seller. Mexico City is full of gas stations. The owners of the gas stations are happy to sell gasoline
because every transaction makes them better off. The owners of cars are happy to buy gasoline because
every transaction makes them better off. But a side effect of all these transactions is that the air becomes
more and more polluted.
Economics studies these kinds of problems as well. Economists seek to understand where and when
markets work and where and when they don’t work. In those situations where markets let us down,
economists search for ways in which economic policies can help.
Changing the Rules
We have explained that microeconomics studies choices and the benefits and problems that arise from
trade. Perhaps most fundamentally, microeconomics studies how people respond to incentives. To
illustrate the importance of incentives, here is an example of what can happen when they go wrong.
In February 1994, an extraordinary scene took place during a soccer match in the Caribbean. Grenada was
playing Barbados, and with five minutes remaining in the match, Barbados was leading by two goals to
one. As the seconds ticked away, it seemed clear that Barbados was going to win the match. Then, three
minutes from the end of the game, the Barbados team did a remarkable thing. It intentionally scored an
own goal, tying the game at two goals apiece.
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
22 After Grenada kicked off again, pandemonium ensued. The Grenada team tried not only to score against
Barbados but also to score an own goal. Barbados desperately defended both its own goal and its
opponents’ goal. The spectacle on the field had very little to do with soccer as it is usually played.
To explain this remarkable sight, we must describe the tournament in which the two teams were playing.
There were two groups of teams, with the winner of each group progressing to the final. The match
between Barbados and Grenada was the last group game and would determine which two teams would be
in the final. The results of the previous matches were such that Barbados needed to win by two goals to go
to the final. If Barbados won by only one goal, then Grenada would qualify instead. But the tournament
organizers had introduced an unusual rule. The organizers decided that if a game were tied, the game
would go to “golden goal” overtime, meaning that the first team to score would win the game, and they
had also decided that the winning team would then be awarded a two-goal victory.
As the game was drawing to a close, Barbados realized it was unlikely to get the two-goal win that it
needed. The team reasoned that a tie was a better result than a one-goal victory because it gave them
roughly a fifty-fifty chance of winning in extra time. So Barbados scored the deliberate own goal. Grenada,
once it realized what had happened, would have been happy either winning or losing by one, so it tried to
score in either goal. Barbados’ strategy paid off. The game finished in a tie; Barbados scored in overtime
and went on win the final.
The organizers should have consulted an economist before instituting the rules of the tournament.
Economics has many lessons to teach, and among the most important is this: people respond to
incentives. The change in the rules changed the incentives that the two teams faced. Because the
tournament organizers had not realized that their rules could lead to a situation in which a team preferred
3
a tie to a win, they failed to foresee the bizarre scene on the field.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
23 You make economic decisions on the allocation of time by deciding how to spend each minute of the day.
You make economic decisions on the allocation of your income by deciding how much to buy of various
goods and services and how much to save.
Economists study how changes in rules lead individual and firms to change their behavior. This is part of
the theme in economics that incentives matter.
Markets are one of the central ways in which individuals interact with each other. Market interactions
provide a basis for the trade that occurs in an economy.
C H E C K I N G Y O U R U N D E R S T A N D I N G
1. When you are choosing how much time to allocate to studying, what incentives affect your decision? Does
the decision depend on how much money you have? Does the decision depend on whether you have a
quiz or an exam coming up in the course? If your instructor changed the rules of the course—for example,
by canceling the final exam—would your choice change?
2. Instead of writing about air pollution in Mexico City, we could have written about water pollution from the
2010 oil spill in the Gulf of Mexico. Would that also be a good example of markets failing?
Next
1 Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (New York: Modern Library, 1994
1776), 14.
2 “Researchers to Scrutinize Megacity Pollution during Mexico City Field Campaign,” University Corporation for
Atmospheric Research, last modified March 2, 2006, accessed January 22,
2011, http://www.ucar.edu/news/releases/2006/mirage.shtml.
3 “Football Follies,” Snopes.com, last modified July 6, 2008, accessed January 22,
2011,http://www.snopes.com/sports/soccer/barbados.asp.
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
24
2.2 The Microeconomic Approach
L E A R N I N G O B JE C T I V E S
1. What is the approach of microeconomics?
2. What are the big questions of economics?
There are several distinguishing features of the microeconomic approach to the world. We discuss
them briefly and then conclude with a look at the big questions of economics.
Individual Choice
One element of the microeconomic approach is individual choice. Throughout this book, we explore how
individuals make decisions. Economists typically suppose that individuals make choices to pursue their
(broadly defined) self-interest given the incentives that they face.
We look at individuals in their roles both as members of households and as members of firms. Individuals
in households buy goods and services from other households and—for the most part—firms. They also sell
their labor time, mostly to firms. Managers of firms, meanwhile, make decisions in the effort to make
their firms profitable. By the end of the book, we will have several frameworks for understanding the
behavior of both households and firms.
Individuals look at the prices of different goods and services in the economy when deciding what to buy.
They act in their own self-interest when they purchase goods and services: it would be foolish for them to
buy things that they don’t want. As prices change, individuals respond by changing their decisions about
which products to buy. If your local sandwich store has a special on a breakfast bagel today, you are more
likely to buy that sandwich. If you are contemplating buying an Android tablet computer but think it is
about to be reduced in price, you will wait until the price comes down.
Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
25
Advise:Why You Wasting Money in Costly SEO Tools, Use World's Best Free SEO Tool Ubersuggest.